Progress in raising the
value of health care — combinations of higher quality outcomes and lower costs
— has been frustratingly slow in the United States. The problem is understood:
Too many providers are paid on the basis of volume of services provided (“fee
for service”), and too few are paid on the basis of the quality of the health
outcome. As a corollary, too much care is provided in a disjointed fashion, and
too often the care of multiple providers for multiple conditions is not
coordinated. Why has change been so slow?
One reason, Ken Thorpe and I argue in a recent op-ed,
is that not all of the policies are pulling in the same
direction. Some of the biggest obstacles have been the
so-called Stark and anti-kickback provisions. These made sense in a
fee-for-service world because doctors should not have a financial incentive,
for example, to refer patients to a surgery center they own (“Stark”) or to
receive payments when a patient uses a particular treatment
(“kickback”). Those decisions should be made on a purely medical basis. But
these laws must be modernized to support the volume-to-value transition
while preserving their original intent.
Here is an example. Recall that patients were
suffering infections because of the devices used in their
colonoscopies. In a fee-for-service world, device manufacturers sell
endoscopes, period. Any further transactions of money from the
manufacturer to the provider would be a kickback — evidence of market
manipulation. In a value-based world, the device manufacturer could bundle
the endoscope with services to help ensure best practices and an
outcome warranty where the manufacturer would cover the cost of any
resulting infection. The incentive would be for best-practice
colonoscopies, but on paper it would would look like a payment from the
manufacturer (the warranty payment) for a particular device — violating
anti-kickback laws.
Similarly, when a patient has multiple illnesses — and especially if one
is a chronic disease — the primary physician/care coordinator should oversee
the treatment plan. Without care coordination, health risks can
arise, including duplication of tests, the implementation of
contradictory treatment plans, the wrong treatment, and the prescribing of
drugs with dangerous interactions. To accomplish this level of
coordination requires that entities communicate and contract with one
another, best practices be adopted and implemented, and the relationships
between health organizations, physicians, nurses, hospitals, and device
and drug manufacturers be strong. But that also means directing the
patient to particular hospitals, doctors, and care.
Both laws complicate the ability of insurers, hospitals, device and
drug manufacturers, physicians, and others to do exactly these
things, and thus engage in value-based contracts. The good news is
that the Department of Health and Human Services has begun a systematic
examination of the Stark and anti-kickback laws by issuing a series
of requests for information asking for comment on barriers to
coordinated care. But Congress should act to ensure these relationships
and activities continue to develop by modernizing the Stark and
anti-kickback laws.
No comments:
Post a Comment