The fuss over
ObamaCare produces confusion and obscures some important realities that deserve
our attention. Much of the political debate creates a polarizing force
like a centrifuge, splitting the pros and the cons into opposing camps that
line up behind positional opinions about whether healthcare is a right or not.
For those opposed to the taxpayer shouldering the financial burden of
providing healthcare to those without insurance coverage, the less the
taxpayers must fork out to subsidize the uninsured the better. All the
while, there is an implied assumption on the part of the entitlement crowd that
just providing insurance coverage for the uninsured is the end game. In
my opinion, we are all laboring under serious misunderstandings of the reality
of the healthcare system and the way the costs are absorbed by society.
I was looking for some
solid research about the cost of the uninsured, and I came across a powerful
and highly useful study from way back in 2003 when the early debate about
universal coverage was just beginning. The approach they took to
analyzing the problem still has significant value today, and what it says helps
shed light on the misunderstandings referenced above. In a preface to the
third chapter of the book Hidden Cost, Value Lost*, there is this
revealing assertion from their research:
The health care
services received by uninsured individuals that they do not pay for themselves
are picked up or “absorbed” by a number of parties, including:
- practitioners and institutions,
both public and private, that serve the uninsured at no charge or reduced
charges;
- the federal government,
localities, and states that support the operation of hospitals and
clinics, both through direct appropriations and implicit subsidies like
the Medicare and Medicaid disproportionate share hospital payments; and
- philanthropic donations.
While uninsured
individuals examined in this research consumed less than half the amount of
healthcare compared to those with full insurance coverage, they did not simply
stop receiving healthcare services altogether. Instead, when their health
conditions worsened to a point where they ultimately sought care, they showed
up at emergency rooms, urgent care centers, and community clinics to be
treated. As everyone knows, ERs are extremely expensive places to receive
care. Further, due to worsened health status because they were not
treated earlier, these individuals ended up with a higher rate of
hospitalization with conditions that were otherwise avoidable had they been
treated in a physician's office before things advanced.
Since these uninsured
people had lower incomes than those with insurance coverage, the out-of-pocket
costs for healthcare represented much higher levels of their total incomes.
Thus, much of the cost of healthcare was non-collectable, and the
unpaid fees were passed on to healthcare providers, local governments, and
charities. In the end, specific to hospitals and community clinics, the
federal government ended up paying subsidies in various different forms (e.g.,
disproportionate share payments, continuing medical education payments, etc.).
Either directly through federal, state, and local governments, or
indirectly through charitable donations, these costs factored their ways into
the tax-payer's wallets. There is "no free lunch" when low-income
individuals go without health insurance.
The next part of the
study goes on to reveal the additional costs that are hidden by the economy.
When people get sick, people miss work until they can get back on their
feet again. That is one of the primary reasons larger employers provide
health insurance: "presenteeism." Absence from work reduces
productivity, and insurance coverage helps minimize the amount of missed time
from the job by ensuring that workers can get treatment quickly and return to
productive work as soon as possible. Therefore, there is a drag on the
U.S. economy when workers are unable to seek healthcare services in a timely
manner, to recover, and to return to productive work.
The authors of this
book came to the following startling conclusion in Chapter 4: Other Costs
Associated with Uninsurance
The Committee’s best
estimate of the aggregate, annualized economic cost of the diminished health
and shorter life spans of Americans who lack health insurance is between
$65 and $130 billion for each year of health insurance forgone. These are
the benefits that could be realized if extension of coverage reduced the
morbidity and mortality of uninsured Americans to the levels for
individuals who are comparable on measured characteristics and who
have private health insurance. These estimated benefits could be
either greater or smaller if unmeasured personal characteristics were responsible for
part of the measured difference in morbidity and mortality between those
with and those without coverage. This estimate does not include spillover
losses to society as a whole of the poorer health of the uninsured
population. It accounts for the value only to those experiencing poorer
health and subsumes the losses to productivity that accrue to uninsured
individuals themselves.
We could pile on to
this limited quantification, as it mentions regarding the "spillover
losses to society as a whole of the poorer health of the uninsured population.”
But letting this limited estimate suffice for the sake of this argument,
the $65 to $130 billion annual cost in 2003, rescaled for inflation and the
lower number of uninsured due to ObamaCare today, still represents an enormous
cost for us to ponder.
The punchline to this
line of thought should be obvious at this point: can we afford to NOT
provide health coverage for these uninsured citizens? Between
the uncompensated care costs we now absorb anyway plus the economic costs
involved with lost productivity, we must reckon with the alternative in a new
light. Regardless of whether you believe that healthcare is a right or a
privilege, we need to look beyond that polarizing division to the true costs
involved and the implications of our decision: to cover or not to
cover? If you think that Healthcare Savings Accounts (HSAs) are
the magic answer, you need to understand that the low-income individuals we are
talking about do not have enough income to set aside anything in a tax-free
account that would be big enough to pay for their healthcare services in the
first place. What is required is decent health insurance that removes the
financial barriers to access healthcare when it can do the most good, which is
early on and easily accessible. Only then can we put people back to work
quickly and productively. Once we do that, they can be fully functioning
and contributing members of the American society.
*Hidden Cost, Value
Lost, Institute of Medicine. 2003. Hidden Costs, Value Lost:
Uninsurance in America. Washington, DC: The National Academies Press. https://doi.org/10.17226/10719;
The fifth of a series of six books on the consequences of uninsurance in the
United States, illustrates some of the economic and social losses to the
country of maintaining so many people without health insurance. The book
explores the potential economic and societal benefits that could be realized if
everyone had health insurance on a continuous basis, as people over age 65
currently do with Medicare.
https://risehealth.org/the-hidden-cost-of-inadequate-health-coverage
Great webpage buddy, I am going to notify this to all my friends and contacts as well.
ReplyDeletehttp://lifesolutionsct.com/medicare-supplement-plans-ct/