Eakinomics: Dynamic
Scoring and the Infrastructure Deal
The top story of the past week was the “deal” struck by a bipartisan group of
centrist Senators and the administration for a total of $1.2 trillion (over
eight years) in infrastructure spending. Much of the subsequent story has
been whether the “deal” was really a deal, with the president admitting that
it was not his intent to link signing an infrastructure bill with the passage
of a subsequent partisan reconciliation bill containing the remainder of his
high-priced agenda.
Lost in this political story is a significant policy development. The New York Times reported:
“Negotiators also agreed to offset some of the cost by assuming that
investing in infrastructure will increase economic growth, by making people
and companies more productive, and thus generate $60 billion more in tax
revenue in the future.” In budget jargon, that is dynamic scoring and
Eakinomics believes it is the first time Democrats have insisted on including
the growth feedbacks in the scoring of legislation.
Democrats' request for dynamic scoring represents a U-turn from their previous
position and is the right thing to
do. Recall that for conventional scoring the Congressional Budget Office
(CBO) and Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT) first build a baseline budgetary
outlook – the revenue raised and spending generated by current laws, assuming
the economy grows (or not) as projected. The “score” of a bill is the change
in revenues and spending produced by the legislation, assuming that the
baseline economic projections are unchanged by the legislation.
In some cases this makes no sense. The whole point of the Tax Cuts and Jobs
Act was to improve economic growth, so it makes sense to do dynamic scoring
of such a proposal by including the additional revenue and reduced spending
produced by faster economic growth. While dynamic scoring has typically been
associated with tax proposals, the logic applies to both sides of
the budget. So, for example, when CBO analyzed the repeal of the
Affordable Care Act, it included the effects of the additional
growth that came with repeal.
In the current circumstances, both sides agree that the infrastructure
proposal should be concentrated on hard, productive infrastructure – roads,
bridges, ports, and the like – that raise productivity and economic output.
Since that is the point of the proposed legislation, Congress should insist
that the CBO score include the dynamic effects on the budget.
Dynamic scoring provides additional information that is valuable to Congress.
There is no reason that the insights into pro-growth policy proposals should
be restricted to the tax side of the ledger.
|
No comments:
Post a Comment