Eakinomics: Drug
Prices (one more time)
‘Tis the Friday before Memorial Day, a day traditionally devoted to
thinking about the link between research and development (R&D) costs
and drug prices. As it turns out, I just recently testified about drug prices,
and the testimony of one of my fellow
panelists argued that R&D costs did not explain the high prices of
drugs, noting: "The money U.S.‐based drug companies
make by charging Americans high prices is 176% greater than what is
needed to fund their global R&D.” I’m not saying the hearing
wasn’t compelling, but I spent the remainder of the time wondering
what should be the relationship between R&D and
revenues.
When I got back to the office, I said to myself, “Doug, you need to
figure this out.” One of the key features of drug development is that the
probability of success (call it p) is very low, as about 8 percent of those drugs that
enter trials actually get approval. Let’s round that to a 10 percent
chance of success. In addition, it takes a long time (let’s call it T) to
develop a drug (let’s assume 10 years), after which — and this gets all
the attention — there will be patent protection that lasts years (let’s
call those years L). We’ll use 20 years as a ballpark. So, the
basic situation is that a firm has to shell out R&D costs every year
(call that D) for 10 years on 10 different drugs so that in the 11th year
one of them will pay off.
For this approach to make sense, the expected (discounted)
revenues have to equal or exceed the (discounted) R&D costs. With
that as the organizing notion, I then did this—
—which tells us that if the R&D costs (D) is $5,000 per dose, then
the break-even launch price of the drug is $98,000 per dose. (This
calculation assumes that the firm has to earn a return of 10
percent.) Most important from the point of view of the basic question, we
observe a firm that has $98,000 in revenue while forking out $50,000 in
annual R&D costs for the next 10 drugs (one of which will pay off) —
a ratio of 196 percent. That figure is in the ballpark of the 176
percent that was held out as too high.
Now one page of scribbling leaves out a lot: global versus U.S. revenues,
knock-off drugs with a higher chance of success, uncertainty over the
entry of competitors, sensitivity to rates of return, and other sources
of costs. But it captures some key realities that dominate the economics:
Drug development is mostly failure with a small probability of success,
the expenses of failure go on for a decade before any revenue shows up,
and any revenue from off-patent sales are so far in the future (30 years)
that they simply don’t matter compared to the on-patent price.
Sure, drug prices seem high. But sometimes doing the math is instructive.
Happy Memorial Day!
|
|
|
No comments:
Post a Comment